Please sign up as a member or login to view and search this journal.
Table of Contents
VoL. XXVIII No. 6
WHOLE No. 144
MATT ROTHERT
STANDARD CATALOG OF
Upited States
Paper Mopey
By Chester L. Krause and Robert F. Lemke
Robert E. Wilhite, Editor
19.95
(plus $2.50 shipping when
ordering direct from the
publisher)
Twice the Information
of Any Other U.S Paper Money Reference!
ALL NEW INFORMATION
• The latest pricing data in up to three grades to
determine the actual value of your notes
• Special 16-pg. "Authentication Guide" details
notes positively identified as counterfeit
• Many rare notes — $500 and $1000 bills —
listed and priced for the first time ever
o )krause
publications
700 East State St. Iola, WI 54990
202 pg. 8-1/2 x 11-in., hardbound
The most comprehensive, up-to-date,
illustrated guide to U.S. paper money
from 1812 to date
• Complete coverage for 175 years of official
paper money circulated by the Federal
Government
• Listings for more than 5,500 currency items
• Over 14,000 market values
• Grading guide providing common-sense
definitions
• In-text cross referencing of Krause/Lemke
and Friedberg numeric systems
• Historic and economic background
information for each major section
• Complete National Bank Note listings with
rarity ratings for each bank of issue
• Identification of all portraits in addition to
the actual illustration provided — for
accurate identification and enhanced
knowledge
Yes! Send me copies of the STANDARD
CATALOG OF UNITED STATES PAPER MONEY,
8th ed. at just $19.95 each.
(U.S. addresses add — $2.50 per book shipping and handling. Non-U.S.
addresses add $5.00 per book. Payable in U.S. funds.)
) Check or money order (to Krause Publications)
Name
IMS IMT
Amount f r books $
Shipping $
Total amount enclosed $
( ) MasterCard ( ) VISA
Credit Card No
Address Expires: Mo. Yr
City
LState Zip
Signature
Mail with payment to Krause Publications, Catalog Dept.
700 E. State St., Iola, WI 54990
SOCI ET 1
OF
p 1.1 , R moNi.iy
C 01.1.1,C"101tS
INC
PAPER MONEY is published every
other month beginning in January by The
Society of Paper Money Collectors. Sec-
ond class postage paid at Dover. DE
19901. Postmaster send address changes
to: Bob Cochran, Secretary, P.O. Box
1085, Florissant. MO 63031.
© Society of Paper Money Collectors,
Inc., 1987. All rights reserved. Repro-
duction of any article, in whole or in part,
without express written permission, is
prohibited.
Annual Membership dues in SPMC are
$20; life membership is $300.
Individual copies of PAPER MONEY
are $2.50.
ADVERTISING RATES
SPACE
Outside
1 TIME 3 TIMES 6 TIMES
Back Cover $152 $420 $825
Inside Front &
Back Cover $145 $405 $798
Full Page $140 $395 $775
Half-page $75 $200 $390
Quarter-page $38 $105 $198
Eighth-page $20 $55 $105
To keep rates at a minimum, advertising must
be prepaid in advance according to the above
schedule. In exceptional cases where special
artwork or extra typing are required, the ad-
vertiser will be notified and billed extra for
them accordingly.
Rates are not commissionable. Proofs are not
supplied.
Deadline: Copy must be in the editorial office
no later than the 10th of the month preceding
issue (e.g., Feb. 10 for March/April issue).
Camera-ready copy will be accepted up to
three weeks beyond this date.
Mechanical Requirements: Full page 42 x 57
picas; half-page may be either vertical or hor-
izontal in format. Single column width, 20
picas. Halftones acceptable, but not mats or
stereos. Page position may be requested but
cannot be guaranteed.
Advertising copy shall be restricted to paper
currency and allied numismatic material and
publications and accessories related thereto.
SPMC does not guarantee advertisements but
accepts copy in good faith, reserving the right
to reject objectionable material or edit any
copy.
SPMC assumes no financial responsibility for
typographical errors in advertisements, but
agrees to reprint that portion of an advertise-
ment in which typographical error should oc-
cur upon prompt notification of such error.
All advertising copy and correspondence
should be sent to the Editor.
Inquiries concerning non-delivery of PAPER MONEY should
be sent to the secretary; for additional copies and back issues
contact book coordinator. Addresses are on the next page.
Official Bimonthly Publication of
The Society of Paper Money Collectors, Inc.
Vol. XXVIII No. 6 Whole No. 144 NOV. /DEC. 1989
ISSN 0031-1162
GENE HESSLER, Editor
P.O. Box 8147
St. Louis, MO 63156
Manuscripts and publications for review should be addressed to the
Editor. Opinions expressed by the authors are their own and do not
necessarily reflect those of SPMC or its staff. PAPER MONEY re-
serves the right to reject any copy. Deadline for copy is the 10th of
the month preceding the month of publication (e.g.. Feb. 10th for
March/April issue). Camera-ready copy will be accepted up to
three weeks beyond this date.
IN THIS ISSUE
HOW CASSIE CHADWICK BROKE THE BANK
by Bob Cochran
177
THE PAPER COLUMN
TREASURY SERIAL NUMBERS BY YEAR FOR THE
EARLY LARGE-SIZE NATIONAL BANK NOTES
by Peter Huntoon
181
THE NATIONAL BANKING SYSTEM by William Litt
185
THE DOLLAR JESSIE JAMES NEVER GOT
by Steven Schroeder
191
RAILROAD NOTES & SCRIP OF THE UNITED STATES,
THE CONFEDERATE STATES AND CANADA
by Richard T. Hoober
193
SYNGRAPHIC VIGNETTES by Robert H. Lloyd
195
SOCIETY FEATURES
INTEREST BEARING NOTES
196
NEW MEMBERS
196
IN MEMORIAM — MATTHEW H. "MATT" ROTHERT
196
MONEY MART
197
Paper Money Whole No 144 Page 173
Society of Paper Money Collectors
OFFICERS
PRESIDENT
Richard J. Balbaton. P.O.B. 911. N. Attleboro, MA 01761-1911
VICE-PRESIDENT
Austin M. Sheheen. Jr., P.O.B. 428, Camden, SC 29020
SECRETARY
Robert Cochran, P.O.B. 1085, Florissant, MO 63031
TREASURER
Dean Oakes, Drawer 1456, Iowa City, IA 52240
APPOINTEES
EDITOR
Gene Hessler, P.O.B. 8147, St. Louis, MO 63156
MEMBERSHIP DIRECTOR
Ron Horstman. P.O.B. 6011, St. Louis, MO 63139
BOOK SALES COORDINATOR
Richard J. Balbaton. P.O.B. 911, N. Attleboro, MA 01761-1911
WISMER BOOK PROJECT
Richard T. Hoober, P.O.B. 196, Newfoundland, PA 18445
LEGAL COUNSEL
Robert J. Galiette, 10 Wilcox Lane, Avon, CT 06001
LIBRARIAN
Walter Fortner, P.O.B. 152, Terre Haute, IN 47808-0152.
PAST-PRESIDENT
Roger H. Durand, P.O.B. 186, Rehoboth, MA 02769
BOARD OF GOVERNORS
Nelson Page Aspen, Richard J. Balbaton, Charles Colver, Michael
Crabb, C. John Ferreri, Milton R. Friedberg, Gene Hessler, Ronald
Horstman, William Horton, Jr., Robert R. Moon, Dean Oakes,
Austin M. Sheheen, Stephen Taylor, Frank Trask, Wendell Wolka.
The Society of Paper Money Collectors was organ-
ized in 1961 and incorporated in 1964 as a non-
profit organization under the laws of the District of
Columbia. It is affiliated with the American Numis-
matic Association. The annual meeting is held at
the Memphis IPMS in June.
MEMBERSHIP - REGULAR and LIFE. Applicants
must be at least 18 years of age and of good moral
character. JUNIOR. Applicants must be from 12 to
18 years of age and of good moral character. Their
application must be signed by a parent or a guardian.
They will be preceded by the letter "j". This letter will
be removed upon notification to the secretary that
the member has reached 18 years of age. Junior
members are not eligible to hold office or to vote.
Members of the ANA or other recognized numis-
matic societies are eligible for membership. Other
applicants should be sponsored by an SPMC mem-
ber or provide suitable references.
DUES - Annual dues are $20. Life membership,
payable in installments, is $300. Members who join
the Society prior to Oct. 1st receive the magazines
already issued in the year in which they join. Mem-
bers who join after Oct. 1st will have their dues paid
through December of the following year. They will al-
so receive, as a bonus, a copy of the magazine issued
in November of the year in which they joined.
PUBLICATIONS FOR SALE TO MEMBERS
BOOKS FOR SALE:
ALABAMA OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP.
1984 Rosene $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
ARKANSAS OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP.
1985 Rothert $17.00
Non-member price $22.00
FLORIDA PAPER MONEY, ILLUSTRATED HISTORY
OF, (softcover) 1980 Cassidy $16.00
Non-member price $19.50
INDIANA OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP,
1978 Wolka $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
INDIAN TERRITORY/OKLAHOMA/KANSAS
OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP.
1980 Burgett and Whitfield $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
IOWA OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP,
1982 Oakes $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
MAINE OBSOLETE PAPER MONEY & SCRIP,
1977 Wait $12.00
Non-member price
$15.00
MINNESOTA OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP,
1973 Rockholt $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
NEW JERSEY'S MONEY, 1976 Wait $15.00
Non-member price $20.00
PENNSYLVANIA OBSOLETE NOTES AND SCRIP
(396 pages), Hoober $28.00
Non-member price $29.50
RHODE ISLAND AND THE PROVIDENCE PLANTA-
TIONS, OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP OF,
1981 Durand $20.00
Non-member price
$25.00
TENNESSEE-THE HISTORY OF EARLY TENNESSEE
BANKS AND THEIR ISSUES,
1983 Garland $20.00
Non-member price
$29.50
TERRITORIALS-A GUIDE TO U.S. TERRITORIAL
NATIONAL BANK NOTES,
(softcover) 1980 Huntoon
$12.00
Non-member price
$15.00
VERMONT OBSOLETE NOTES & SCRIP,
1972 Coulter $12.00
Non-member price $15.00
All cloth bound books are 8 1/2 x 11"
Write for Quantity Prices on the above books.
ORDERING INSTRUCTIONS
1. Give complete description for all items ordered.
2. Total the cost of all publications ordered.
3. ALL publications are postpaid except orders for less than 5
copies of Paper Money.
4. Enclose payment (U.S. funds only) with all orders. Make your check
or money order payable to: Society of Paper Money Collectors.
5. Remember to include your ZIP CODE.
6. Allow up to six weeks for delivery. We have no control of your
package after we place it in the mails. Order from:
R.J. Balbaton, SPMC Book Sales Dept., P.O. Box 911, N. Attleboro, MA 02761-0911
Library Services: The Society maintains a lending library for the use of the members only. For further information.
write the Librarian - Walter Fortner, P.O. Box 152, Terre Haute, IN 47808-0152.
Page 174
Paper Money Whole No. 144
The ULTIMATE United
States Obsolete Bank Note
Reference Is Here!
UNITED STATES
OBSOLETE
BANK NOTES
1782-1866
By James A. Haxby
Four volumes,
8 1/2)(11, hardbound
r
STANCARD CATALOG OF
Paper Money Whole No. 144 Page 175
UNPRECEDENTED!
Mail to: Krause Publications, Catalog Dept.
700 E. State St., Iola, WI 54990
Send me copies of the Standard Catalog of
World Paper Money, Vol. II, General Issues, at $45.00
each.
Yes! Send me sets of the all new Standard
Catalog of United States Obsolete Bank Notes, 1782 - 1866
at $195.00 per st.
Amount for books
Shipping
Total amount enclosed
Name
Address
City
State Zip
) Check or money order (to Krause Publications)
) MasterCard/VISA (order billed as Krause =
Publications)
Credit Card No.
Expires: Mo. Yr
Signature
(Obsolete Bank Note Book, U.S. addresses, postage
included. Foreign addresses add $18.00 for shipping. For
the World Paper Money book, U.S addresses at $2.50 per
book; foreign addresses add $4.50. Payable in U.S. funds)
Credit card customers dial toll-free
800-258-0929
8 am-5 prn, CST, Mon.-Fri. Non-orders and
Wisconsin callers, please use our regular business line,
715-445-2214. FFE JA5
You'll find over 2700 pages in four comprehensive,
hardbound volumes. This landmark reference work offers you:
• Vast amounts of original research, including the most
authoritative treatment of counterfeit, raised, altered and
spurious notes to date! Where notes of altered origins are
documented, unaltered notes are listed as well to help you
trace the actual origins of issues in your collection.
• The most complete list of state bank engravers (imprints)
ever assembled! One more way to attribute your notes.
• Prices for each note! For the first time you'll know exactly
what a note is worth. Improve your collecting rewards
significantly with this vital market data!
• Every bank note documented to have been issued is listed.
More than 77,000 in all! Use this information to trace those
puzzling notes from your collection.
• Each listing is accompanied by catalog number;
denominations of issue; engraver identifications; issue dates as
engraved or hand-written on the notes; overprint colors; and
where no photo is available, a detailed description. It's a
comprehensive study!
• Many notes are pictured for the first time anywhere! More
than 15,000 photos make the Standard Catalog of United
States Obsolete Bank Notes a tremendous asset in attributing
your notes.
Books will be available in early November. Reserve your copy
now!
Still Available—The Standard Catalog of World Paper
Money, Vol. II, General Issues. It's Albert Pick's classic listing
of government legal tender worldwide!
$
$
Page 176
A4i1HILlei loll, ll^lll
Paper Money Whole No. 144
I'll li II
\\O'
I
:r I he 1[1
WE ARE ALWAYS
BUYING
■ FRACTIONAL CURRENCY
■ ENCASED POSTAGE
■ LARGE SIZE CURRENCY
■ COLONIAL CURRENCY
WRITE, CALL OR SHIP:
IP— — 4111110 411■
...;
•CU RIR E inc.
LEN and JEAN GLAZER
(718) 268.3221
POST OFFICE BOX 111
FOREST HILLS, N.Y. 11375
,( 1 C I F. T
I , \ ( )
• r 'Et
Charter Member
Paper Money Whole No. 144 Page 177
66
. . this was how the rich got that way—when you needed something, you just wrote a
check!"
How
r■assie
hadwick
Droke the
liank
by BOB COCHRAN
This story doesn't deal with someone winning big
at the gambling table; rather, it's how one woman
ruined the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin,
Ohio, and how she destroyed the careers of sever-
al respected bankers in the process. Until she was
convicted she was one of the most successful "con
artists" of her time.
CASSIE CHADWICK
Copied from an original photograph made about 1897. and secured
through the courtesy of C.A. Farnesworth of the
Union Trust Co.. Cleveland
"MISS ELIZABETH BIGLEY, HEIRESS TO A FORTUNE"
C ASSIE Chadwick's real name was Elizabeth Bigley. Shewas raised in Eastwood, near Woodstock, in Ontario,Canada. She was an excellent and imaginative student;
her teacher was Cassie Cushing (the source of her alias). Dan
Bigley, Elizabeth's father, was a dollar-a-day section boss on the
Great Western Railway and farmed in his free time. Elizabeth
often dreamed of being wealthy, and when she was still quite
young she experienced her first taste of "the good life."
She was an attractive young girl, and wise beyond her years.
At the age of thirteen she sold her virtue for fifty dollars (she in-
sisted on cash) to a local farmer who was attracted to her and
authorized a fictitious letter to herself from a non-existent lawyer
informing her that an uncle (also fictitious) had passed away.
leaving her fifteen thousand dollars. She skipped school and
took the train to the nearest town, Woodstock, and showed the
letter to the clerk in the town's only bank. The clerk was some-
what disappointed that Elizabeth only wanted to deposit thirty
dollars cash, but he was fooled by the bogus letter. He gave her
a book of blank checks, and explained to her how they were
used. To Elizabeth, this was how the rich got that way—when
you needed something, you just wrote a check!
In short order, she wrote checks for a gold bracelet, two
dresses for herself and a skirt for her sister, and a package of
business cards (the cards stated in large letters "Miss Elizabeth
Bigley," and underneath in smaller letters "Heiress to a
Fortune"). She checked into a local hotel, and the next morning
went out to eat and window-shop. When she returned to the
hotel she was arrested for passing bad checks and taken to the
local jail. When she appeared before the magistrate the next
day, a constable told the court about her family and referred to
Elizabeth as "the odd one." The magistrate decided that she was
mentally disturbed and ordered her release. The goods she had
purchased were returned to the merchants; the cost of the hotel
room and the business cards was taken from the deposit she had
made at the bank.
"MADAME LYDIA DeVERE"
The next year Elizabeth left Eastwood for good to hone her skills
at deception. In Toronto she became a prostitute; later in Tole-
do she billed herself as a clairvoyant, "Madam Lydia DeVere";
she and a man she had duped into believing that she loved him
were arrested and charged with fraud and forging checks and
promissory notes of prominent individuals. The case drew extra
attention from the local press because the attorney for the dupe.
one Joe Lamb, claimed that Lamb had been hypnotized by
"Madame DeVere" and made to do her bidding. The tactic
worked, and Lamb was acquitted.
Elizabeth's lawyer rebutted the charges against her for forgery
by claiming that there was no absolute proof that she had per-
sonally forged the signatures on the worthless documents. On
the fraud charge, her attorney attempted to confuse the jury by
raising the question of what constituted fraud: Elizabeth had
claimed to be one "Florida G. Blythe," a fictitious name that she
had made up. Her attorney questioned whether it was illegal to
pretend to be someone who did not exist; to impersonate a liv-
ing person was one thing, but to claim to be someone who did
not exist was not fraud, or so he claimed. The prosecution faced
the prospect of losing its case. but on the last day of the trial they
shocked Elizabeth and her attorney by producing a surprise wit-
ness—a woman of means from Cleveland whose real name was
"Florida G. Blythe"! The real Florida G. Blythe testified that she
had never heard of "Madame Lydia DeVere" and had never
had any dealings with her.
Elizabeth was convicted of fraud and sentenced to a term of
nine years and six months in the state penitentiary in Columbus.
Ohio. She served three years and six months of her sentence
Page 178
before being pardoned by Governor William McKinley. In 1894
Elizabeth turned up in Cleveland under the name of Mrs. C.
(Cassie) L. Hoover. To finance her extravagant lifestyle she be-
came a madame in a Cleveland brothel. Shortly after she began
this work she was introduced to a shy doctor, Leroy S. Chad-
wick. Amazingly she convinced him that she had no idea of the
type of establishment she was living in—only that the girls came
and went as they pleased and that some of them appeared to
have questionable morals! Chadwick was a lonely man, and,
falling for Elizabeth's apparent innocence and charm, invited her
to move into his home.
CASSIE CHADWICK, "FINANCIER"
Leroy Chadwick was quite wealthy through an inheritance, and
Elizabeth went to work on him. In February of 1896 they were
married in Pittsburgh, ostensibly to keep her description and
photograph out of the Cleveland papers. Cassie convinced her
new husband that his financial affairs were in a shambles, and he
was only too glad to let her (and a lawyer of her choosing) man-
age his properties. She redecorated their home on Euclid
Avenue and spent his money lavishly on gifts for her friends.
After she had taken several of her young women friends on a
trip to Europe, she found that she and her new husband were
broke. Not only that; Cassie had purchased costly gifts for her-
self and her retinue overseas, and the bills were coming in.
As she had discovered when she was young, the best place to
get money was a bank. She knew that it would be risky in Cleve-
land, so she chose the Citizens National Bank of nearby Oberlin,
Ohio. (The Citizens National Bank of Oberlin was originally
chartered in August 1863, and assigned charter number 72 by
the Comptroller of the Currency. When its twenty-year charter
expired, the bank was liquidated on June 1, 1882 and reorgan-
ized. The bank retained its original name but was assigned a new
charter number, 2718.) Cassie told the president of the bank,
Charles B. Beckwith, that she wanted to make an endowment
to the local Oberlin College, but that her funds were not avail-
able at the moment, and she asked if he would furnish her
$13,000 on her personal note. Beckwith thought that this might
be the start of a profitable arrangement; he knew that Euclid
Avenue was an affluent section of Cleveland, and he may have
been aware that Dr. Chadwick was (formerly) a wealthy man.
The bank's capitalization at the time was only $60,000, and the
legal limit of a loan was $6,000; so Beckwith loaned her the
money out of his own pocket. He generously offered to deliver
the check to the college personally, and Cassie agreed.
During the conversation Cassie decided that Beckwith could
be useful to her. She confided to him that she was unable to
Paper Money Whole No. 144
manage her finances, and that her finances were substantial; she
needed the advice and guidance of a knowledgeable banker
such as he. She also confessed that the source of her wealth was
due to the fact that she was the illegitimate daughter of none
other than Andrew Carnegie!
She told Beckwith that Carnegie had regretted his sin, and in
order to make it up to her he had furnished her with her person-
al notes for large sums (plus interest) that were due the following
year. This would make it appear that she was "earning" the
money, rather than Carnegie simply giving it to her. She asked
Beckwith if it was possible to borrow money against the notes,
and he eagerly agreed. Cassie produced a forged note for
$250,000 bearing the signature of Andrew Carnegie and signed
the note over to Beckwith and Albert B. Spear, cashier of the
bank. Beckwith gave her a receipt stating that she had that
amount of money on deposit at the bank.
Cassie's next stop was the Wade Park Banking Company in
Cleveland, where she showed her receipt to the firm's secretary,
Iri Reynolds. Reynolds was familiar with the Chadwick family,
although he had never before met Dr. Chadwick's new wife.
She used the receipt to establish a credit of $125,000, and
promptly wrote a check against it for $100,000. Then she took
a train to New York, where she used the money to open an ac-
count at the Lincoln National Bank.
She then:
1. Wrote a check for $300,000 on her new account at the
Lincoln National Bank in New York and mailed it to Charles
Beckwith at the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin. She instruct-
ed him to repay her loan of $13,000 and to deposit the rest in
her account there.
2. Went back to the Wade Park Banking Company and gave
Reynolds a check on the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin for
$125,000, to cover her loan. Because she had repaid the loan
so promptly, Reynolds advanced her a new loan of $350,000.
3. Wrote a check against her new loan at the Wade Park
Banking Company for $300,000, and sent it to the Lincoln Na-
tional Bank of New York to cover the first check drawn on her
account and deposited with Beckwith. (The way I figure it, Cassie
"cleared" $75,000 on this series of transactions; if I'm wrong, I'm sure
one of our members more versed in math will correct me.]
Cassie went back to Oberlin to confer with Beckwith; she told
him that "her father" wanted her to purchase a building owned
by the wealthy financier Charles Schwab, one of her neighbors
in Cleveland; but Carnegie did not want it known that he per-
sonally was interested in the building, so he had asked Cassie to
handle the deal. She told Beckwith that Carnegie had offered
her a 10% commission, which could be over $100,000 if she
were able to acquire the property for him; if Beckwith would
Third Charter Red Seal
note issued by the Citizens
National Bank of Oberlin,
Ohio. Arthur Spear signed
this note as cashier, and
Charles B. Beckwith signed
as president, although his
signature has almost com-
pletely faded.
„46-",ae
of
zlf •4.n‘
cC ,/,441 4-t-,xe 'IL
,.-4 c. 1> ,,,,,*4" ,A1:71
.1, 4,,a,..-‘4 =c--,,z,,Z.,-4.--
tLaw,..._,,.,/ e(„4- yef,--- ei„,f/
Paper Money Whole No. 144
help her he could have half of the commission. Beckwith had
some reservations about the deal, but agree to help.
She called Beckwith a few days later and told him she had
talked to Schwab. It seemed that Schwab had another offer on
the property, but if Cassie could furnish him with earnest money
of $150,000 he would consider her offer. Beckwith, perhaps
seeing his half of the commission disappearing, told Cassie to
write Schwab a check for $150,000 on her account at the Citi-
zens National Bank; he would send her a note to sign, to meet
the legal requirement for the transaction. Several weeks went by
and Beckwith had not received the signed note. When he was
finally able to reach Cassie by telephone she told him that the
deal had fallen through and that she had torn up the note.
Cassie continued to conjure up money based upon her "se-
cret" relationship to Andrew Carnegie. She furnished Iri Rey-
nolds with an envelope for his safekeeping that she said con-
tained securities (consisting of, among other things, stock of the
Caledonia Railway of Scotland, which was owned by
Carnegie). Reynolds accepted the envelope without investigat-
ing its contents and issued her a receipt for $5 million!
To satisfy other loans, she produced a bogus trust agreement
stating that Andrew Carnegie held in trust for her property
amounting to over $10 million, which consisted of:
2,500 shares of stock of the Great Western Railway of Eng-
land and Wales, valued at $2,100,000;
1.800 shares of stock of Caledonia Railway of Scotland,
valued at $1,146,000; and
Bonds of the United States Steel Corporation of New
Jersey, bearing interest at 5%, valued at $7,000,000.
After she had married Leroy Chadwick, Cassie had become a
member of the Euclid Avenue Baptist Church, of which John D.
Rockefeller was also a member. Although she apparently never
attended a service, she did call on the pastor of the church and
confided her "secret" to him. She told him delicately that she
was in need of a short term loan. It's possible that she was at-
tempting to get an introduction to Rockefeller; instead the
pastor, Charles Eaton, wrote a letter to his brother John, who
was a prominent lawyer in Boston. Included in the letter was a
promissory note for $500,000 from Carnegie to Cassie, which
Cassie had furnished him, along with a list of the securities sup-
posedly on deposit at the Wade Park Bank, which she claimed
were now worth over $7 million.
Eaton helped Cassie to arrange a loan from one of his clients,
Herbert D. Newton, a banker from Boston. She had wanted to
obtain $200,000 from him, but he offered her a check and a
personal note totaling $129,000 in exchange for her promissory
note of $190,000; he explained that the first year's interest of
5% was deducted first, leaving $190,000, and that the differ-
ence between the $129,000 and $190,000 was made up of the
bank's commission and handling charge.
She took Newton's check and note and deposited them at the
Lincoln National Bank of New York, apologizing for the earlier
confusion she had caused previously when she had overdrawn
her account. When she returned to Ohio, she visited Charles
Beckwith at the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin and wrote him
a check on the Lincoln National Bank to cover his outstanding
loan to her. Showing Beckwith her receipt for $5 million from
the Wade Park Bank, she arranged another loan from his bank
for $80,000. When she got back to Cleveland, she wrote a
check on the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin (for $300,000)
and sent it to the Lincoln National Bank of New York—after she
had deposited Newton's note and check, she had promptly
overdrawn that account — AGAIN.
Page 179
This is Cassie's assignment of a forged $250,000 promissory
note to Charles Beckwith and Arthur Spear, president and
cashier respectively, of the Citizens National Bank of Oberlin,
Ohio. It reads:
"I hereby sell, assign and transfer unto C.B. Beckwith and A.B.
Spear, for a valuable consideration and a full settlement of all
their claims against me, a certain promissory note dated Jan 7th
1904, signed by Andrew Carnegie, for Two hundred and fifty
thousand dollars ($250,000) due one year after date with in-
terest at 5% per annum.
And I hereby certify that I am the lawful owner of the said note,
that it is free from all offsets, and I leave the right to bargain and
sell the same, and this is my free will and act. Signed. C.L.
Chadwick.”
Cassie then went back to Beckwith and amazingly convinced
him to advance her the $300,000 to cover the check she had
written on his bank to the Lincoln National Bank. She furnished
him with two of Andrew Carnegie's supposed promissory notes
(totaling $300,000) to secure the loan. Shortly after this, Beck-
with convinced Arthur Spear, the cashier of the bank, to join
him in loaning Cassie $102,000; Beckwith had also helped her
to borrow over $1 million from various banks and individuals.
based upon the supposed securities on deposit at the Wade Park
Bank. Thoughtfully, Cassie furnished Beckwith with a copy of
her will; in it she listed and described all of her securities, gave
him her power of attorney, and made him the executor of her
estate.
THE END OF CASSIE CHADWICK
Back in Boston, Herbert D. Newton had not received any pay-
ments from Cassie. He and his lawyers attempted to negotiate
some payments from her on her note, but she kept putting them
Page 180
off. Finally, on November 22, 1904, Newton brought suit
against her in the Federal Court in Cleveland, for the outstand-
ing amount of the loan, $190,800. He also requested that the
court restrain the Wade Park Bank from disposing of the $7.5
million being held there in trust.
When word of the suit reached Oberlin, Beckwith explained
to his bank's questioning directors that the bank was in no
danger, since the bank held a note of $500,000 from one of the
wealthiest men in the world. But he refused to divulge
Carnegie's name, to protect Cassie's "honor." Newton wasn't so
discreet—he also held a $500,000 note signed by Carnegie,
and he revealed this to the court and the press.
Several financial institutions rushed to join the suit by Newton
against Cassie, among them The American Exchange National
Bank of Cleveland, the Savings Deposit Bank of Elyria, Ohio,
and the Euclid Avenue Savings and Trust Company of Cleve-
land. When Andrew Carnegie was asked by the press about his
"illegitimate daughter" he replied that he had never heard of the
woman in question.
The judge hearing Newton's suit ordered Iri Reynolds at the
Wade Park Bank to produce the securities he was holding for
Cassie Chadwick, and when they were examined and deter-
mined to be worthless, an arrest warrant was issued for Cassie.
She was found in New York and brought back to Cleveland for
trial
The trial began on March 6, 1905 and lasted six days. During
the trial Andrew Carnegie was an interested spectator. A report-
er asked him if he had any plans to prosecute Cassie himself, but
Carnegie demurred, saying that she had ironically proven that
his credit on his name alone was A-1. Handwriting experts sup-
ported Carnegie's earlier statement that the signatures on the
docucments were not his. The jury found her guilty and she was
sentenced to a term of ten years in the Ohio State Penitentiary.
Cassie was a celebrity even in jail, and she granted many in-
terviews to the curious press. At one point the warden was
charging twenty-five cents to admit her visitors, until this fact ap-
peared in print; the result was that all of her visitors except a son
were barred. She became obsessed with her funeral, planning it
in great detail. When she died in prison on October 10, 1907 all
of the arrangements had been made; a tombstone was already
waiting for her at the cemetery in Woodstock that she had se-
lected for her burial. She had even written her own eulogy,
which was read at the service held on October 14, 1907.
Paper Money Whole No. 144
FATE OF THE CITIZENS NATIONAL BANK
OF OBERLIN, OHIO
Early in Beckwith's dealings with Cassie the Citizens National
Bank of Oberlin had been examined. He had concealed her
original loan of $13,000 from the examiner by negotiating a
temporary loan to himself, which he repaid immediately after
the examination.
The next scheduled examination of the bank took place in
April 1904. At that time the outstanding loan of Cassie Chad-
wick was $220,000, over $200,000 beyond the legal limit of the
bank. Beckwith apparently convinced the examiner that the
loan was adequately secured, by showing him the forged Car-
negie promissory note. The examiner reported the loan in his
report, but indicated that he did not feel the bank was in danger
of sustaining a loss; he reported that the loan had been made to
a "C.A. Chadwick," but did not indicate that this was a woman.
Further, he did not indicate that the security for the loan was a
note from Andrew Carnegie. Kane states, "Had this examiner
advised the Comptroller of the Currency that the recipient of this
large loan was a woman and that the security consisted of a note
of Andrew Carnegie, the Comptroller would have made an in-
quiry in regard to this woman and why Andrew Carnegie had
executed his note to her for such a large sum of money, as Mr.
Carnegie was not in the habit of having his notes in national
banks."
On November 28, 1904, six days after Newton's suit against
Cassie Chadwick was filed, the Citizens National Bank of Ober-
lin suspended operations and was placed in the hands of a re-
ceiver. So complete was the faith of President Beckwith in
Cassie that for several days after the bank suspended operations
he still believed that she would come forward and meet her obli-
gations. When Beckwith was asked why he had never ques-
tioned the forged documents, he stated that he thought the Car-
negie signatures were genuine, because he had seen Carnegie's
signature in the newspaper! Arthur B. Spear. the cashier of the
bank, was indicted, tried and convicted of making false entries in
the books of the bank, for the purpose of hiding the excessive
loans from the bank examiners and the Comptroller; he had
certified that Cassie had a certain deposit in the bank when she
did not. In his trial, his defense was that he had made these en-
tries at the direction of President Beckwith, and that he had not
personally profited from any of the transactions (he had even
(Continued on page 195)
A satirical note produced
by W.J. Wells in 1905.
Cassie's trial in 1905 drew
enormous attention from
the press, and Mr. Wells
apparently felt it was a
timely item. The bank in
the left oval is "Busted."
Paper Money Whole No. 144 Page 181
Treasury Serial Numbers by Year
for the Early Large-Size National Bank Notes
THE PAPER COLUMN
by Peter Huntoon
The tables that accompany this article provide the first serial
numbers delivered to the Comptroller of the Currency each year
for the various sheet combinations then in use. These data were
abstracted from Comptroller of the Currency (various dates).
Huntoon (1985a,b) and Huntoon and Raymond (1985) pre-
sented tables showing dates during which various treasury serial
block letters were in use. These data were useful in pinning
down delivery dates to the Comptroller of the Currency (and
therefore printing dates) for the popular plate combinations.
However, for the little used combinations, such as the 50-100,
one treasury block letter spanned most if not all of the period of
use within a particular series. Thus, the beginning and ending
dates were of little value because they spanned many years.
This article is designed to rectify that problem. For example, if
your note from an Original Series 10-10-20-20 plate has
treasury serial 3500, you can use Table 1 to determine that it
was printed in 1866. A dash in the table indicates that no notes
were printed from the combination during that year.
There were occasional out-of-sequence deliveries from the
Bureau of Engraving and Printing to the Comptroller of the Cur-
rency during the late Series of 1882 brown back and Series of
1902 red seal printings. These odd deliveries involved a total of
only a few thousand sheets. The cutoff serials used in Tables 5
and 6 are the first serials for the "regular" deliveries and are
therefore somewhat arbitrary.
A few cautions are in order. (1) All serial numbers listed in
these tables are sheet numbers, therefore each note on the sheet
had the same number. (2) All Original Series serial numbers list-
ed in these tables were printed in red ink unless specifically la-
beled "blue." (3) The second set of Original Series treasury serial
numbers for the 1 1 1 2, 5 5 5 5 and 10-10-10-20 combina-
tions were printed with blue ink and without treasury letters.
They are appropriately labeled in the tables if they were in use at
the beginning of a specific year. (4) Treasury serial letters were
prefixed to all Original Series serial numbers in 1869 if such let-
ters were not then in use except for the 50-100, 500-500-500-
500 and 1000-1000-10001000 combinations. Serial number-
ing was consecutive in the changeovers between the unlettered
and lettered varieties. (5) Some treasury block letters used to
number notes in a few combinations did not progress in alpha-
betical order. (6) The Original Series 20, 20-50, 50 and 50-50-
100 combinations listed on Table 2 were denominations printed
from larger plates. These part-plate combinations were each
given independent blue treasury serial number sets. For more
details on each of these points, see Huntoon (1985a,b).
Out-of-sequence treasury serial letters occurred as follows:
5-5-5-5 Series of 1875, Y followed Z beginning in 1893; 5-5-
5-5 Series of 1882 brown backs, T then M followed Z in 1898:
and 10-10-10-10 Original Series, W followed Z in 1875.
In addition to adding prefix letters, other measures were taken
to secure the treasury serial numbers in May, 1896. Most im-
Table 1. First treasury serial numbers delivered to the Comptroller of the Currency by year for the Original Series National Bank Notes, part 1.
10-10- 10-10- 10-10- 10-20- 10-50- 20-20- 20-20- 20-20- 20-20-
Year 1-1-1-2 1 1 2 2 5-5-5-5 10-10 10-10-10-20 20-20 20-50 50-100 50-100 20-20 20-50 20-100 50-100
1863 - 9 9 - - -
4 8016 5023 22 29
7
99 blue
10 1 -
57 50 43 36
5 9 874133 blue 384580 500472 15 9835 10877 24524 2914 11641
6 490467 blue A141 blue D356514 564984 668142 blue 1022 13949 - 19098 61161 3789 22532
7 B167591 D942828 612107 959717 blue 17293 - 20562 23841
8 B304076 E66435 617200 A10124 17893 1371 - - 71096 24683
9 B498137 1177194 621557 A41856 18193 - 21187 71226 4094 25183
1870 B764893 A10512 blue 1338865 Z629824 A92820 T18693 R1521 X23694 V72626 W26880
1 C181394 A10862 blue E752620 Z660086 A241262 Y3529 T20710 R1621 X25869 V79366 U4194 W29590
2 C858660 6776887 Z747673 A664071 T25831 R1821 X30146 V89667 04469 W33120
3 D375793 A15332 blue K711947 Z818338 B47509 14629 T28916 - X36332 V96199 U4669 W36412
4 D737424 L523555 Z876553 B302473 14929 - X37664 V110510 U5589 W41592
5 1159954 A17598 blue P82494 2961039 B765498 T33130 R2220 A349 blue X54210 V141642 U6539 W49659
Table 2. First treasury serial numbers delivered to the Comptroller of the Currency by year for the Original Series National Bank Notes, part 2.
50-50- 500- 3x500+
Year 50-50 50-100 50-100 100-100 500 1000 1000 4x500 1000 4x1000 20 20-50 50 50-50-100
1864 64 78 85 92 113 106 -
5 120 blue 45132 3483 1395 1869 541 370 120 127
6 527 blue 193051 7578 4669 9710 2123 804 - 134 -
7 235214 9970 5933 10661 932 -
8 2212 blue 240045 10070 6008 10774 2236 -
9 243145 10342 6168 10904 - -
1870 B2275 blue 250366 P10872 N6523 M11101 K2258 - -
1 82889 blue 261708 P11548 N7634 M11324 K2308 L952 -
2 B6403 blue 303544 P15730 N9936 812411 K2480 L1052 -
3 B6903 blue 345025 P16502 N10649 814172 K2495 L1152 - X22 blue
4 B7203 blue 387838 P20290 N12423 M14662 K2712 L1252 - X2786 blue K85 blue A22 blue A71 blue
5 89510 blue 491674 P24058 N14458 M16602 K2722 - 645 652 X34004 blue A922 blue
Page 182
Table 3. First treasury serial numbers delivered to
Paper Money Whole No. 144
the Comptroller of the Currency by year for the Series of 1875 National Bank Notes, part 1.
1-1- 10-10- 10-10- 10-10- 10-10- 10-20- 10-50- 20-20- 20-20- 20-20 20-20-
Year 1-1-1-2 2-2 5-5-5-5 10-10 10-20 20-20 20-50 50-100 50-100 20-20 20-50 20-100 50-100 50-50
1875 Al - Al Al Al Al Al - - Al Al - Al Al
6 A17357 - A543356 A45726 A277067 A201 A201 Al - A551 A5056 - A301 A201
7 A479085 Al B972146 A208276 B90069 - A4498 3101 Al Al2101 A28600 Al A7551 A4151
8 B233805 - E211376 A343391 B608127 - A11021 - - A20776 A45984 -
2
16651
9 - - 11213996 A425763 390973 A701 Al2661 - A24375 A53811 - ',11367495A7951
1880 - - K129791 1522641 D467719 4801 133550 169930 117800
1 K982706 A600191 D785503 - A17416 - A37300 A76643 A18200 A8201
2 - U327976 A751925 E440661 - A20716 A1051 - A50837 A92337 A23258 A11051
3 - V409360 A808345 1163529 Al201 A22356 - - 156612 1100525 - 128766 114451
4 - X167705 A857295 11521526 A1534 A22756 - A143 A61757 A111852 - A28866 A17702
5 - X852017 A893108 H963325 - A23156 - - A66152 A119367 A298I6 A19452
6 2108767 A904508 K85775 - A23711 A67147 Al22312 -
7 2267867 A909008 K143795 A67272 Al22994 - - A20402
8 2359409 A911397 K176098 A67482 Al23264 A29876 A20602
9 2477459 A913587 K225088 - A23761 A67208 Al23374 - -
1890 2583409 A917432 K265750 - A23811 A68621 Al23919 -
1 2697589 A922192 K316320 - A23866 A68861 Al25064 - A21002
2 - - 2811269 A927242 K340381 A69176 Al25364 - A29926 A21082
3
4 -
2929319
Y85169
A933042
A942967
1<460836
1<547479
A69651
471416
Al25514
Al26014 -
-
-
A21202
A22572
5 1214704 A949667 K614436 A71441 - - - A22812
6 1289567 A954642 K656919 - 1126124 -
7 Y350819 A959822 K740209 - Al26540 - -
8 Y438344 A963897 K789990 - Al26990 423222
9 - Y524879 A972222 K851709 - - -
1900 1557679 A974747 K878799 - Al27170 -
1 - Y581039 A978902 K986099 - - - - -
2 - Y587039 A980927 N10189 A30066
Table 4. First treasury serial numbers delivered to the Comptroller of the Currency
by year for the Series of 1875 National Bank Notes, part 2.
50-50-
year 50-100 50-100 100-100 500 500-1000 4x500 4x1000
1875 Al Al Al Al -
6 A20497 A1001 A51 A151 Al
7 A71422 A6701 A841 A1051 A41 Al
8 A116486 A8417 A1941 A2511 -
9 A146062 A11277 A2041 A2971 A661
1880 A176398 Al2847 A2531 A3071 A771
1 A196971 A13447 A2631 A3141 A781
2 A279406 A19847 A6102 A3891 A1788 Al
3 A332807 A22803 A9227 A3931 A1818
4 A374589 A25683 A9977 A4041 A1843
5 A410453 - - - -
6 A417854 - A10652 -
7 A420146 - - -
8 A421695 - A10752 -
9 A424807 - A10787 -
1890 A427583 - A10812 -
1 A431891 - A10837 -
2 A435658 - -
3 A440504
4 A447186
5 A448659
6 A449975
7 A453795
8 A455878
9 A458909
1900 A459169
1 A462419
2 -
Paper Money Whole No. 144
Page 183
Table 5. First treasury serial numbers delivered from the Bureau of Engraving
and Printing to the Comptroller of the Currency by year for the
Series of 1882 Brown Back National Bank Notes.
Year 5-5-5-5 10,-10-10-10 10-10-10-20 50-100
1882 Al - Al Al
3 A233904 - A209919 A20359
4 A600492 - A588264 A55061
5 B123607 - B327 A105647
6 D443488 - B945744 A207441
7 E122475 - D140270 A235707
8 E627230 - D497712 A258455
9 H285155 - D856198 A301294
1890 H787443 - E99294 A319861
1 K319812 - E395461 A348532
2 N78448 - E825478 A393623
3 N851764 - H362435 A437569
4 U311904 - K327992 A513903
5 V546634 - K961860 A561500
6 W638839 - N489203 A613638
7 Y120744 - R323434 A679923
8 Z717136 - R988147 A733737
9 M429936 - U40946 A850973
1900 A839536A - U724416 A900821
1 D100111D - X913986 B94503
2 D873829D - Z642907 B186068
3 E987839E - B888597B B279487
4 K70781K - E899794E B373746
5 N453581N - N37345N B471274
6 R381314R Al R717547R B541467
7 T612929T A77401 T811863T B578393
8 U803309U A219201 U884838U B615041
9 A273226 - _
Table 6. First treasury serial numbers delivered from the Bureau of Engraving
and Printing to the Comptroller of the Currency by year for the
Series of 1902 Red Seal National Bank Notes.
Year 5-5-5-5 10-10-10-10 10-10-10-20 50-100
1902 Al Al Al
3 A161017 - A428902 A14143
4 A592834 - B437670 A60722
5 B115136 - D761166 A105056
6 D923406 Al K921325 A226281
7 K501349 A242054 T270483 A310964
8 N474961 A758997 V689772 A389531
orirriC ,
fl
yagadutto"
st.
/// Y6(1 . X///
Page 184
Paper Money Whole No. 144
A significant $50 Original Series note printed from the unusual 20-20-20-50 plate combination. Table 1 re-
veals that its treasury serial number, V171566, was printed in 1875. The First National Bank of Geneva,
Ohio, was a 19-year bank organized under the Act of February 25, 1863. It was forced to liquidate on June 1,
1882, so was reorganized on May 2. 1882, under the same title but new charter number 2719. The original
charter number, 153, was reassigned to the bank on April 11, 1917. It turns out that this was both the highest
charter number so reassigned, and the last to regain a lost charter number from the 1882 reorganizations.
(Photo courtesy of Doug Walcutt)
portant was that brackets were introduced as terminators at the
ends of numbers with prefix letters and at both ends in the unlet-
tered 50-100, 500-500-500-500 and 1000-1000-1000-1000
combinations. More subtle but equally important was that gaps
between teasury letters and the serial numbers were closed. In the
early issues using prefix letters, low numbers came with gaps be-
tween the treasury letter and the beginning of the number. These
spaces were closed by moving the letter against the number.
Table 7 lists transcribing errors that appear in Huntoon
(1985a,b). The most interesting correction shows that 10-10-
10-10 combination Series of 1882 brown backs were being
printed as late as one year after the other brown backs combina-
tions ceased. Regular production from the 10-10-10-10 plates
stopped on September 4, 1908. However, one lone 1909 print-
ing was made for The First National Bank of Flatonia. Texas,
charter 4179, utilizing bank serial numbers 1376 through 1625,
and treasury serial numbers A273226 through A273475. These
sheets were delivered on March 22, 1909. The reason for the
post-March, 1908, 10-10-10-10 brown back printings is un-
known. However, Series of 1902 red seals were printed simul-
taneously with Series of 1902 dates backs between June and
December of 1908 as well.
Table 7. Corrections to errors in "National Bank Notes with Treasury Serial
1 and 1000000, parts I & II."
Part I, Paper Money, whole number 118:
Table 4 5-5-5-5 Original Series Jul
(page 170)
Table 4 5-5-5-5 Original Series Jul
(page 170)
Table 4 5-5-5-5 Series of 1882 Brown
Mar 23, 1908 (page 171)
Table 4 10-10-10-10 Series of 1882 Brown Backs
Mar 22, 1909 (page 173)
Mar 22, 1908 should be
28, 1863 should be Jul 28, 1864
29, 1863 should be Jul 29, 1864
Backs Mar 22, 1908 should be
Part II, Paper Money, whole number 119:
Table 1 50-50 519 blue should be 120 blue (page 217)
Table 2 5-5-5-5 Mar 22, 1908 should be Mar 23, 1908 (page 218)
Table 2 10-10-10-10 Mar 22, 1908 should be Mar 22, 1909 (page 218)
Table 5 50-50 Original Series Dec 28, 1865 519 blue should be 120 blue
(page 223)
(Continued on page 190)
Stars and Stripes, on this First Charter "Lazy Two," was engraved by Louis Delnoce.
by WILLIAM LITT
Mechanics Nalional Ranh
/4//, , /,„„,
uz
Paper Money Whole No. 144 Page 185
The
NATIONAL BANKING SYSTEM
Serving Commerce and Industry at the
Expense of Agriculture
HE National Banking System was originally con-
ceived as a response to the financial burdens placed
upon the United States by the Civil War. The pri-
mary purposes of the System were to raise revenues for
the Union by establishing an outlet for the sale of govern-
ment bonds, and to create a uniform paper currency that
appeared trustworthy enough to circulate at its face
value. Although the National Banking System was fairly
successful in achieving its initial goals, it grew to be some-
thing far more significant than a temporary currency re-
form occasioned by the war.
Despite the many ramifications of the National Bank Acts
passed in 1863 and 1864, there appears to have been little con-
cern in Congress about the long-term impact of the National
Banking System. Most legislators viewed it as a temporary
measure necessitated by the war and as such, a necessary evil.
Opponents of national banking mainly consisted of defenders of
state bank circulation, and although many Congressmen ques-
tioned the bill's prospective effectiveness in financing the war,
they were willing to try almost anything to generate the enor-
mous amount of money required to support the Union army.
Margaret G. Myers, in one of the earliest non-contemporary ex-
plorations of the interaction between national banks and the
New York capital market, contends that:
...nearly all were blinded by the war to the importance of
the act as a permanent peace institution. They voted for it,
not because they felt any enthusiasm for it, but because the
President and the Secretary of the Treasury had declared it
to be necessary—the same reason which had influenced
the vote for the bill making the greenbacks legal tender. It
seems exceedingly doubtful if the act could have passed Con-
gress without the war emergency to serve as an excuse, for
that body was neither anxious to legislate on banking nor con-
scious of the full significance of their action when they did
legislate.'
Later implications aside, the National Bank Acts of 1863 and
1864 established a system of nationally chartered banks that
were required to purchase United States bonds as part of their
incorporation agreements. These charters were to be obtained
through the newly created office of the Comptroller of the Cur-
rency, and included minimum capital requirements that ranged
from $200,000 in cities with populations of 50,000 or more to
$50,000 in towns of 6,000 or less. Each nationally chartered
bank had to deposit with the Comptroller, United States bonds
equal to one third of its capital, and not less than $30,000. In
addition to receiving the interest from the bonds, each bank was
entitled to issue national bank notes totaling up to 90 percent of
the par or market value, whichever was lower, of the bonds on
deposit. The Gold Standard Act of 1900 lowered capital re-
quirements for small-town banks and permitted the issuance of
bank notes up to 100 percent of the value of the deposited
bonds. Initially, circulation of national bank notes was limited to
a total value of $300,000,000 for the entire country, although
this limit was raised by $54,000,000 in 1870 in response to
complaints that banks outside of the Northeast had received a
disproportionately small share of the total circulation.' The Re-
sumption Act of 1875 eliminated all restrictions on the amount
of national bank note circulation.
Although the concept of a bond-backed, uniform currency
was a vital innovation of the National Banking System, the most
Page 186
significant aspects of the System in terms of economic develop-
ment were its reserve requirements, its restrictions on real
estate-backed loans, and its lack of provisions for branch bank-
ing. Because of a limited understanding of economics and the
primitive structure of the nation's capital markets at the inception
of the National Banking System, it appears that these regula-
tions were intended simply to ensure the soundness of national
banks, rather than to actively promote economic growth. Never-
theless, the structure of these regulations almost certainly aided
the unprecedented growth which the United States enjoyed
during the heyday of the National Banking System.
Reserve requirements were at the core of the National Bank-
ing System's contribution to the growth of the New York money
market, which was the source of most of the capital employed in
the development of "modern" industry and the railroads. The
National Currency Act of 1864 formalized the rather haphazard
antebellum system of banker's balances by creating three classes
of national banks and ascribing certain reserve requirements to
each type.' New York was designated as the nation's central re-
serve city, joined in this category by St. Louis and Chicago in
1887. 4 Eighteen cities were designated as reserve cities, with this
number increasing to 47 during the next fifty years. National
banks in the three central reserve cities were required to main-
tain cash reserves equal to 25 percent of their deposits. Reserve
city national banks could hold the reserves of other national
banks, as could central reserve city banks, and were also re-
quired to maintain 25 percent reserves. However, only half of
these reserves had to be held in lawful money: the other half
could be in the form of deposits in New York, and later Chicago
and St. Louis, national banks. Non-reserve and central reserve
city national banks were required to sustain 15 percent reserves,
of which three-fifths (i.e. 9 percent) was permitted to be held as
deposits in reserve city and central reserve city banks. This re-
serve system was responsible for the accumulation of funds in
the nation's capital markets, most notably New York, and since
it allowed several banks to view the same assets as their required
reserves, it actually created a money pyramid which, as will be
seen later, accentuated the panics that occurred during the exist-
ence of the system.
The provisions limiting the loan portfolios of national banks
were almost certainly intended to promote the security of the in-
dividual banks by ensuring the greatest possible liquidity of their
assets. The national banks in New York, Chicago, and St.
Louis, the central reserve cities, were forbidden from making
loans on real estate. Other national banks were permitted to
grant loans of less than five years' maturity as long as each loan
amounted to less than half of the appraised value of the land be-
ing used as collateral. In addition, banks were not permitted to
have total real estate loans that exceeded 25 percent of their
capital. As a result, real estate loans accounted for a very small
portion of national bank assets, and national banks were effec-
tively prevented from granting mortgages. This preemption of
mortgage activity from national banks, in addition to raising the
ire of farmers, was partially responsible for the resurgence of
state-chartered banks after their rapid decline following the
1865, 10 percent tax on state bank notes.' Another very signifi-
cant result of the preemption of granting mortgages from nation-
al banks was that they were left with a larger amount of money
to invest outside of the immediate communities which they
served. Most of this money found its way to national banks in
New York, where it was held as additional bankers' balances be-
yond required reserves. Not only did reserves and other bank-
ers' balances earn interest from the New York banks, but this
money was normally invested in the call loan market by the big
Paper Money Whole No. 144
Wall Street banks for their client national banks throughout the
country'.
Another important aspect of the system was that it made no
official provision for branch banks. Although the original Acts of
1863 and 1864 did not directly address the question, subse-
quent interpretations by Comptrollers and Treasury Secretaries
during the first few years of the National Banking System made
it quite clear that branches outside of a bank's home city would
not be tolerated.' The restrictions on branch banking were grad-
ually relaxed in the system's later years, but it was not until the
late 1920s that national banks were permitted to branch exten-
sively within their home states, and truly nationwide branching
was unlawful until very recently. These restrictions on branch
banking encouraged national banks to keep bankers' balances in
excess of required reserves with their correspondent banks in
the reserve and central reserve cities in order to benefit from
services, such as check clearing, which these banks offered.
There is little doubt that the National Banking System aided
economic development during the entire period from its crea-
tion until at least the establishment of the Federal Reserve Sys-
tem and the outbreak of the First World War. The manner in
which reserves were held tended to "pyramid" funds in New
York City, where they were almost invariably invested in the call
loan market and the stock market. Furthermore, the preemption
of mortgages from national banks encouraged them to invest
their assets in non-real estate loans, usually various commercial
enterprises. For rural national banks which had few opportun-
ities to make business loans locally, this meant depositing funds
with other, mainly national, banks in larger cities. These funds,
as as stated, drew interest and were loaned out by the big-city
banks to various industries, large and small, as well as railroads
and similar concerns. The provisions of the National Banking
Acts, which were construed as barring banks from operating
branches, also had a substantial impact on economic growth,
tending to reinforce the pyramiding of reserves and the creation
of bankers' balances in excess of required reserves.
While the National Banking System was a boon to commer-
cial and industrial growth. it was less kind to rural America. The
system, although in many respects a distinct improvement over
antebellum banking, had a number of flaws. These flaws tended
to hit harder amongst the agrarian population than elsewhere, a
fact that did not go unnoticed by farmers and other critics of na-
tional banking.
Problems and Deficiencies
of National Banking
If the Government had offered a reward for the most skill-
fully constructed scheme by which productive industry
could be placed permanently and securely under tribute to
speculators and idlers, the authors of the National banking
system would have been entitled, without question, to a re-
ward and to a diploma for their ingenuity.'
—James B. Weaver, Call to Action
Weaver, the People's Party candidate for President in 1892,
devoted a chapter to the weaknesses and abuses of the National
Banking System in his widely read treatise A Call to Action. The
famous subtreasury plan, which was a cornerstone of the Popu-
list platform was, in part, designed to combat certain aspects of
national banking, which were particularly odious to farmers.
Despite the fact that it provided a uniform, trustworthy paper
currency for the first time in the nation's history, the National
Banking System was under fire from the moment of its creation.
During Congressional debates, opposition came from states'
Paper Money Whole No. 144
rights advocates who were opposed to the dual banking system
that the National Bank Act would usher in. As previously men-
tioned, it is unlikely that the act would have passed were it not
viewed as a wartime necessity. If the vehemently anti-Federalist
Southern legislators had taken part in the vote, it is virtually cer-
tain that the System would never have been adopted. Despite
improvements in the security of banknotes and in banking effi-
ciency, the National Banking System legitimized certain com-
ponents of antebellum banking that proved unsuitable to the sta-
bility of the United States' economy, and introduced a few new
wrinkles which worked to the detriment of the rural population.
Several recent studies of national banking have recognized
that the practice of small-town bankers maintaining substantial
balances with big-city banks existed long before the Civil War. In
the days before checking accounts, these balances were used by
city banks to redeem the banknotes of hinterland banks. They
also assisted in the seasonal exchange of cash for crops and of-
fered an unofficial but relatively secure depository for the assets
of rural banks. When checks became commonplace, bankers'
balances greatly facilitated check-clearing. The National Bank
Acts merely gave the federal government's imprimatur to a well-
established system. There were, however, a number of new
twists that accentuated the institution's flaws.
The system of fractional reserves strongly encouraged non-re-
serve city national banks to maintain substantial bankers' bal-
ances with reserve city banks, since these reserves usually
earned interest for the banks and were thus far more appealing
than holding reserves in the form of vault cash. Since banks in
New York and most other large cities paid interest on bankers'
balances, many banks deposited funds far in excess of the re-
quired reserves.' The fact that interest was paid on bankers' bal-
ances, coupled with the interdiction on mortgages imposed on
national banks, tended to syphon funds from agriculture and in-
to the call loan market and the stock market of New York. Mod-
ern debate has turned on the question of whether national banks
operated as price discriminating monopolists in rural areas. Al-
though that question will be examined later, it is more important
to note that farmers were either able to obtain credit only at
usurious rates of interest, or were unable to obtain it at all.
While noting that data are not comprehensive, Helen Hill Up-
dike states that farmers typically paid 10 to 18 percent for loans,
and sometimes as high as 30 percent. These rates fly in the face
of state usury laws that set legal limits on interest at 6, 8, or at
most 12 percent, and the federal limitation of 7 percent on all
loans. In contrast, Updike cites typical loan rates for businesses
on the New York money market as being about 4 percent.'°
John Skelton Williams, then Comptroller of the Currency, car-
ried out a 1914 study of interest rates and concluded that:
...some national banks in every part of the country and
nearly all national banks in certain sections, have been
charging rates of interest on some of their loans which are
not only illegal and usurious, but are intolerable."
The self-reliant American farmers sensed that they had fallen
victim to the "thralldom of the money power,' and were quick
to place the blame at the feet of the National Banking System
and a nebulous monopoly of Eastern bankers led by the House
of Morgan. Updike cites Populist journals that attribute the credit
situation to the "millionaire bankers" representing Eastern inter-
ests who are "immense, secret, cunning, unscrupulous" and
creators of a system of "financial tyranny."' She also quotes
Populist agitator Mary Elizabeth Lease, who stated: "We wiped
out slavery and by our tariff laws and national banks began a
system of white wage slavery worse than the first.""
Page 187
In addition to the usurious interest rates which national banks
were able to exact from farmers, the National Banking System
drew fire from agrarian activists for a number of other reasons.
Foremost among these was the contention that national bank
notes provided an inelastic currency that was unsuited to the
seasonal demands of agriculture and compounded the defla-
tionary tendencies of the gold standard. During the early years
of the system, the problem was primarily one of physical availa-
bility of banknotes. Since branch banking was not permitted, the
original requirement of at least $50,000 capitalization served to
deprive many small towns of a national bank. Initially, state-
chartered banks often filled the gap. However, the increasingly
heavy federal taxes placed on state bank notes eventually drove
many state banks to convert to national charters. The National
Bank Acts called for a maximum national bank note circulation
of $300,000,000, to be apportioned according to population
and existing banking facilities. Despite this provision, when the
rush for national charters occurred in the aftermath of the final
10 percent tax on state bank notes, existing state banks that con-
verted were assigned note circulation on a first-come, first-
served basis. Richard Sylla has calculated that by October 1,
1866—when most state banks had converted to national status
and $280 million of the authorized $300 million had been is-
sued —notes issued to banks in the New England, Middle At-
lantic, and "East North Central" regions of the United States ac-
counted for $262 million of the total.' Sylla asserts that the
South and "West North Central" regions, which at the time har-
bored almost 40 percent of the country's population, were allot-
ted only about $10 million of the national bank note cir-
culation: 6 The state of Connecticut had more national bank
note circulation than Michigan, Iowa, Minnesota, Kansas, Mis-
souri, Kentucky, and Tennessee combined. The per capita cir-
culation of Rhode Island was $77.16, while that of Arkansas
was $.13. "
Although an additional $54,000,000 was authorized in
1870, with preference given to banks in areas that had not re-
ceived a fair portion of the original authorization, and all restric-
tions on total circulation were removed in 1875, the shortage of
national bank notes only grew worse. The reason for this de-
crease in circulation was simple: in 1880, the United States be-
gan to run a budget surplus due to unexpected increases in cus-
toms revenue; in response, the Treasury started to reduce the
national debt by retiring all callable bonds and purchasing others
in the open market. This led to large premiums on bonds, which
substantially reduced the profitability of issuing bond-backed
notes. The total amount outstanding declined from about $300
million in 1880 to $126 million by the decade's end. Although
circulation increased again in the 1890s, when bond prices fell,
it did not regain its earlier peak." Although the decline in na-
tional bank note circulation was offset, in part, by increases in
the amount of other types of paper money — especially silver
certificates—in circulation, rural activists viewed the process as a
rather sinister phenomenon. It did not seem fair to them that the
amount of currency in circulation should depend upon the pro-
fitability of holding bonds to back the paper money issued. In es-
sence, the amount of paper money issued depended upon how
much profit could be made by private bankers by issuing it. In
the words of James B. Weaver:
The fundamental vice which underlies the National
banking system is this: It is the surrender of one of the high-
est duties and powers of the Government to the control of
private speculators to be used for personal gain. It is an at-
tempt to harmonize the interests of private adventure with
the demands of the whole people at all times for a stable
and adequate money supply.'
Page 188
Another contemporary critic saw the laws establishing national
banks as being " . . of the same character of vicious legislation
that demonetized silver. - And that they were " . . . conceived in
infamy and . . . for no other purpose but to rob the many for the
benefit of the few.""
High interest rates and depressed prices resulting from a
limited amount of currency in circulation were aspects of the Na-
tional Banking System which hit farmers especially hard. How-
ever, the inelasticity of national bank notes, coupled with the
"pyramiding" of reserves and bankers' balances in New York,
had dramatic repercussions for the entire country.
In addition to long-term inelasticity caused by its dependence
on the bond market and government fiscal policy rather than the
needs of the business community, national bank currency was
equally unresponsive to short-term business requirements. Dur-
ing periods of prosperity, when an increase in the money supply
was desired, national banks had more attractive options than
purchasing government bonds, so their note circulation de-
clined. In times of recession, the process was reversed and cir-
culation increased despite a decrease in the demand for money.
Just as the needs of the business community had little effect on
national bank note circulation, so too was the System inade-
quate to provide the extra funds needed by farmers for planting
in the spring and for harvesting and transporting crops in the
fall.
This inelasticity was compounded by the fractional reserve
system. The system of "pyramided" reserves in New York tend-
ed to immobilize a substantial portion of small-town national
bank reserves, with the effect that the seasonal demands for
funds by farm communities led to a massive withdrawal of funds
from New York by rural banks twice per year. During these per-
iods of reserve withdrawal, credit in the New York money mar-
ket tightened and interest rates rose, leading to mild crises twice
each year. Usually, the financial community was able to pull
through until the heightened agricultural activity spent itself, but
occasionally the demand for funds was larger than anticipated
or the banks had difficulty with liquidating their loans. Under
these circumstances, the typical response of New York banks
was to suspend payment of their obligations to their correspond-
ent banks in the countryside. Thus localized financial stringen-
cies snowballed into nationwide panics in 1873, 1884, 1893
and 1907. Herman E. Krooss and Martin R. Blyn, in A History
of Financial Intermediaries, offer a synopsis of the role of nation-
al banks and bankers' balances in the Panic of 1873:
Another similar seasonal difficulty developed in the spring
of 1873, but this time liquidation of loans and securities was
difficult because of weaknesses in railroad securities. Three
brokerage houses suspended operation in May, but by
June the situation was so much improved tha businessmen
decided that a new spurt of prosperity was about to begin.
Unfortunately, this optimistic view was ill-founded. Rail-
roads could not continue to meet their fixed charges, capi-
tal imports declined from their high level, and the stock
market began to fall. Banks began to contract credit, coun-
try banks clamored for funds, and hoarding by individuals
increased. In September seven New York banks, holding
72 percent of total interbank deposits, could not liquidate
their loans fast enough to meet the increasing demand for
funds, and in a short time they were operating with a re-
serve deficiency. Businessmen and banks had nowhere to
turn, and with progressively accelerated speed, the New
York money market headed for inevitable disaster.'
A particularly ironic aspect of the system of fractional reserves
Paper Money Whole No. 144
was that it frequently allowed the city banks to impose the in-
elasticity of the money supply on their correspondent country
banks. When the cyclical agricultural demand for cash coincided
with urban financial stringencies, and city national banks sus-
pended payment of bankers' balances to the hinterland, it forced
the country banks to bear the brunt of financial crises; the irony
was that the city banks remained relatively secure at these times
because of the "cushion" of specie in their vaults, much of which
actually consisted of deposits owed to country national banks.
Helen Hill Updike cites this component of financial panics as a
probable explanation for the difference in failure rates between
country and city banks and the fact that city banks failed more or
less randomly, while large numbers of country banks failed dur-
ing panics."
The crux of the problem was the fact that fractional reserves
and bankers' balances created de facto central banking in New
York City. Ordinarily, this might not have been detrimental to
the economy as a whole. The difficulty arose, as demonstrated
previously, in times of financial stringency coupled with a heav-
ier-than-usual demand for money. When demand for funds in-
creased, banks were unable to meet it because no provision had
been made to hold emergency reserves. Since the 25 percent
reserve requirement was a minimum, below which reserve city
national banks were legally unable to go, it acted to preserve the
soundness of the individual bank at the expense of the economy
in general. Even if national banks were willing and able to issue
more currency, the process normally took one to two months.
The series of panics that occurred approximately once each
decade during the period from 1863 to 1914 can be attributed
to the lack of an official central bank and lender of last resort as
much as they can be to inelastic currency supplies. New York,
and to a lesser extent Chicago, national banks were forced to
operate as lenders of last resort in times of financial difficulty, but
they lacked the ability to control the money supply and stabilize
the money market and, of course, were interested first and fore-
most in making money themselves rather than operating simply
for the good of the United States.
Central reserve city national banks were aware of their posi-
tion as de facto central bankers. Frequently they attempted to
expand their loans in times of credit stringency," although at
higher interest rates, but this was usually too little too late.
Another method of mitigating financial crises was through clear-
inghouse certificates. Clearinghouses had developed during the
1850s and 1860s in most large cities to facilitate check clearing
and money transfers between banks in the same city. During the
Panic of 1907, clearinghouse certificates were issued in small
denominations for use by the general public, thus giving some
flexibility to the currency. The Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908
was passed in response to the 1907 crisis, and one of its most
important provisions was the establishment of a system for creat-
ing clearinghouses known as National Currency Associations,
which could issue additional amounts of national currency,
identical to other national bank notes but backed by commercial
paper, non-federal government bonds, and clearinghouse cer-
tificates. A stiff tax was imposed on these bank notes in order to
encourage their quick retirement after the crisis for which they
were issued had passed. Although the Act expired in 1915 and
was superseded in 1914 by the Federal Reserve System, it func-
tioned quite well during the 1914 panic occasioned by the out-
break of the First World War. Several analysts of national bank-
ing have concluded that the system might have continued oper-
ating successfully without the creation of the Federal Reserve if
the Aldrich-Vreeland Act had been extended and some form of
Paper Money Whole No. 144 Page 189
The portrait of Secretary of the Treasury John Sherman, on this Third Charter note, was engraved by G.F.C.
Smillie.
deposit insurance established." Although space does not permit
an exploration of the Federal Reserve System, suffice it to say
that the economic conservatism of the period during which it
was created, in addition to a reluctance to establish a European-
style central bank, made it a painfully imperfect solution to the
problems of national banking until the sweeping reforms of the
New Deal era.
Conclusion
One of the most frustrating aspects of researching the Nation-
al Banking System is the fixation on economics bound up in vir-
tually every work on the subject. While bringing modern tech-
niques of economic analysis to historical questions is both valid
and extremely useful, there is a tendency to ignore or downplay
the human components of a given situation. The National
Banking System itself was rather complex, and any exploration
of the topic must necessarily delineate the provisions of the most
significant laws pertaining to national banks. However, most of
the scholars who have turned their attention to national banking
have been economists or economic historians; conversely, most
of the contemporary criticism of the National Banking System
came from agrarian activists and other reformers, and was
highly impressionistic in nature. Although several modern
analyses of the system have attempted to reconcile the impas-
sioned complaints of nineteenth century farmers with hard-core
economic analysis, the typical result is an essay filled with tables,
formulas, and equations, which happens to have a few quotes
from Populist journals thrown in as an apparent afterthought.
The most important recent essays on national banking have
been primarily concerned with two questions: 1) did national
banks operate as price discriminating monopolists in rural areas?
and 2) did small-town national banks take funds that should
have been invested locally, probably in agriculture, and send
them instead to reserve and central reserve cities to be invested
in the stock and call loan markets?
Although farmers had long blamed the high interest rates and
discriminatory lending policies of national banks on some
shadowy "eastern monopoly," Richard Sylla was the first writer
to systematically tackle the question of whether rural, southern,
and western national banks operated as individual monopolists.
Sylla concluded that barriers to entry, such as minimum capital
requirements, prohibition of mortgage loans, and ceilings on
note-issue, coupled with the 10 percent tax on state bank note
issues in an era when checks were not commonly used outside
of major cities, led to monopoly power for small-town national
bankers. The fact that bankers' balances, including three-fifths of
required reserves, could be held in distant cities and earn inter-
est allowed country banks to keep the local supply of loanable
funds artificially low. As proof of this he cites markedly higher
interest rates in rural areas and the south and west in general, as
well as higher profits for national banks in these regions than for
those in eastern cities." Helen Hill Updike, in a book subtitled
"The Farmers and the National Banks, 1870-1900," questions
Sylla's conclusion. While allowing that his hypotheses are con-
sistent with observed reality, she notes that bankers' balances
were not a creature of the National Banking System, existing at
least forty years before the system's creation. More importantly,
she questions why city bankers did not place funds in rural areas
where monopoly returns could supposedly be earned. Ignoring
the fact that an influx of capital from cities would eliminate the
"artificially low level of loanable funds" held by country national
banks, she suggests that bankers maximized real rather than
money rates of return, and that real rates of return for country
bankers were lower than for city bankers because of a greater
risk of failure." Both Sylla and Updike agree, however, hat the
structure of the National Banking System did indeed serve to
cull funds that might have been invested locally in agriculture
and instead send them to serve commerce and industry in the
nation's financial centers.
Sylla and Updike, while noting that the effects of national
banking on farmers were cruel and resulted in a great deal of
hardship, both contend that the system resulted in a more effi-
cient allocation of funds to the most rapidly expanding segments
of the economy. It is doubtless true that the National Banking
System pumped a great deal of necessary capital into industrial
and commercial ventures and thus contributed to the unprece-
dented economic growth of the United States between the Civil
and First World Wars. However, to dismiss agriculture as a de-
clining segment of the economy is to ignore the human suffering
brought about by this "efficient" allocation of funds. Sylla at his
most sentimental stated:
The process of bank fund mobilization was a harsh one as
far as the nation's farmers were concerned .... But the his-
tory of modern economic growth is one of the declining rel-
ative importance of agriculture and the rising importance of
industry; in the United States, banking developments
merely hastened these trends."
Page 190
A century after the fact, it is easy to view the National Banking
System dispassionately. Panics are a thing of the past, the dark
days of '93 and '07 are relegated to passages in dusty books and
the occasional clearinghouse certificate seen in a coin dealer's
showcase. Although national banking as it existed before the
Great Depression is long gone, the words of James Weaver con-
jure up visions of the terrible poverty and long odds that faced
late nineteenth century farmers, and the role which the National
Banking System played in their economic oppression:
.. the American people are within the hands and com-
pletely at the mercy of a lot of grinding speculators . . . what
shall we say of the social structure when built upon a feeble
and vicious financial foundation-when it depends for its
strength and efficiency upon the speculative interests of a
lot of adventurers?"
The National Banking System did indeed contribute substantial-
ly to economic growth in the United States, but at what cost?
Notes
' Myers, New York Money Market, p. 218.
2
Sylla, "The United States, 1863-1913," pp. 243-244.
Ibid., p. 249.
Treasury, National Bank Act, p. 62.
White, The Regulation and Reform of the American Banking Sys-
tem, 1990-1929, pp. 23-25.
Myers, pp. 237-250.
White, p. 14.
a Weaver, A Call to Action, p. 400.
9 Myer, p. 236.
'° Updike, The National Banks and American Economic Develop-
ment, 1870-1900, p. 27.
" Annual Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1915, Vol. I,
Washington, D.C., 1916, p. 23. Cited in Updike, p. 28.
12 Broken Bow, NE, Beacon, 1895. Quoted in Updike, p. 26.
13 Updike, p. 26.
" Ibid., p. 27.
Sylla, pp. 243-244.
10 Ibid., p. 245.
" Krooss and Blyn, A History of Financial Intermediaries, p. 100.
is Carson, ed. Banking and Monetary Studies, pp. 22-23.
19 Weaver, p. 395.
2° Frank Drew, quoted in Hicks, The Populist Revolt, p. 92.
Krooss and Blyn, p. 101.
22 Updike, p. 56.
23 White, p. 70.
" Carson, ed., p. 38.
Sylla, pp. 246-247.
" Updike, p. 25.
20 Sylla, p. 258.
28
Weaver, pp. 400-401.
Bibliography
Campen, James T. and Mayhew, Anne. (Mar. 1988). "The National
Banking System and Southern Economic Growth: Evidence from
One Southern City, 1870-1900." The Journal of Economic History
48, no. 1: 127-137.
Carson, Deane, ed. (1963) Banking and Monetary Studies. Home-
wood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.
Goodwyn, Lawrence. (1978). The Populist Moment. New York: Ox-
ford University Press.
Helderman, Leonard C. (1931). National and State Banks. Cam-
bridge, MA: The Riverside Press.
Hickman, John and Oakes, Dean. (1982). Standard Catalog of Nation.
al Bank Notes. Iola, WI: Krause Publications.
Hicks, John D. (1931). The Populist Revolt. Minneapolis: The Univer-
sity of Minnesota Press.
Krooss, Herman E. and Blyn, Martin R. (1971). A History of Financial
Intermediaries. New York: Random House .
Paper Money Whole No. 144
Myers, Margaret G. (1931). The New York Money Market. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Perlo, Victor. (1957). The Empire of High Finance. New York: Interna-
tional Publishers.
Sylla, Richard E. (1972). "The United States, 1863-1913," in Camer-
on, Rondo ed. Banking and Economic Development: Some Les-
sons of History. New York: Oxford University Press.
Treasury Department. (1930). The National Bank Act as Amended De-
cember 1, 1930. Washington: United States Government Printing
Office.
Updike, Helen Hill. (1985). The National Banks and American Eco-
nomic Development, 1870-1900. New York: Garland Publishing,
Inc.
Weaver, James B. (1892). A Call to Action. Des Moines: Iowa Printing
Co.
White, Eugene Nelson. (1983). The Regulation and Reform of the
American Banking System, 1900-1929. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Huntoon (Continued from page 184)
REFERENCES CITED
Comptroller of the Currency, various dates, Ledgers showing receipts
of national bank notes from the engravers: U.S. National Archives,
record group 101, Washington, DC.
Huntoon, P., 1985a, National bank notes with treasury serial 1 and
1000000, part I: Paper Money, v. 24, pp. 167-174.
Huntoon, P., 19856, National bank notes with treasury serial 1 and
1000000, part II, Paper Money, v. 24, pp. 214-225.
Huntoon, P., and W.K. Raymond, 1985, National bank notes with
treasury serial 1 and 1000000. part III: Paper Money, v. 24. pp.
266-268, 277.
STATEMENT OF OWNERSHIP, MANAGEMENT AND CIRCULATION
IA lo of PueficsBoo
PAPER MONEY
10 PUBLICATION NO 2 Omo ol ;ono
°I°1 3 ITIrkrill
Sept. 13, 1989
J. itopooncy or Isouo
Hi-monthly
An.ZollY""
6
1
20. 00
4 Pereelere 1.1•11, /Weir... ol [.own 011peo 01,91.11. 15.ceo. Coy. ...sy. sm. one VP. Led • I Mn annual
1211 N. Dupont Highway, Dover, Delaware
19901
1211 e N. Dupont Highway, Dover, Delaware
19901
Dover Litho Printing Co., 1211 N. Dupont Highway, Cover, Delaware
19901
Gene Hessler, P.O. Box 8147, St. Louis, Mo.
63156
Dover Litho Printing Co., 1211 N. Dupont Highway, Dover, DE 19901
rud
/I-
.afr o
Fa Nom* Com... Melling sae...
The Society of Paper Hones Collectors
ee
„ere ,.. °
..... eed or., Boeur11,1oldors C.n.no o, 07.9 1 P. ,B•M B , ..,... T,c. ',BBL." , , BL.L..”LB LB .• .' ...
Full Nome Complolo BlellIn. Addrm
9 C . IE.
rt I
El it:LP 'InVn:"' I: 't!,':::%°;'f ,°=. ZrZ ft,1':,".n".""‘"`"'°"""'
m 0 of 1•Lon
A Taal No Copies. P
2,000 1900
2 Alo
revu e su d, 1,772 1763
C Tool Z"°'""'"" 1,772 1763
8 8
F oul Mu 0 on of C ..d.
1,780 177'
fll'i 220 129
2,000 1900
cer/Hy that rheas
"."5"^-•--""'""°' '';'"
ma shove ere cos
en made by
rrect end complete I -gal-9..z 7., ...e.-,.(j i?.,./44
PS PoIrn 3626, ow. 1927
Paper Money Whole No. 144
The Dollar
Tessie
ames
Never Got
(Or did he?)
by STEVE SCHROEDER
This innocent looking dollar bill is a reminder of
the most famous bank robbery in the history of
Minnesota.
O N September 7, 1876, eight men entered Northfield torob the First National Bank. They were Bob, Jim andCole Younger, Clel Miller,Charlie Pitts, Bill Stiles (also
called Bill Chadwell) and two men thought to be Frank and
Jesse James. Three of the men (Pitts, Bob Younger, Frank
James) entered the bank. The assistant cashier, J.L. Heywood,
and two tellers, A.E. Bunker and F.J. Wilcox, were working
there that day. The robbers demanded that Heywood unlock
the safe. He said he couldn't unlock the safe, which was true
since it was already unlocked with the door shut. The tellers
would not open the safe either, and the robbers were not smart
enough to not try opening it themselves. After a few minutes of
this cat and mouse business, one of the robbers shot and killed
Heywood and the three grabbed a few dollars in the tellers'
cages and fled.
Page 191
While this was going on inside the bank the other five gang
members were standing watch at various places outside. J.S.
Allen and Henry Wheeler, a medical student home from studies
at the University of Michigan, noticed the men entering the
bank. Allen tried to enter the bank, but was stopped by Clel Mill-
er. When this happened Allen ran around the corner shouting,
"Get your guns boys, they're robbing the bank."
By this time shots had been fired in the bank. Allen owned a
hardward store where he passed out shotguns to several towns-
people who used them against the robbers. Wheeler found an
old army carbine and three shells at the hotel. Anselm Manning,
a carpenter, found an old breech-loading rifle and some ammu-
nition. Although the others were armed only with shotguns.
Manning and Wheeler did real damage. Manning could not at
first get a good shot at any robber, so he shot one of their
horses, figuring this would effectively disable the gang. After re-
loading he shot Cole Younger "in a vulnerable though not vital
place" (as the historian Huntington wrote in 1895—which could
have many meanings). Reloading again, Manning took careful
aim and shot Stiles through the heart. Meanwhile Dr. Wheeler,
firing from an upper window, killed Clel Miller with a single shot.
Finally, Manning shot Bob Younger in the elbow, shattering the
bone.
At this point the robbers fled as best they could. Stiles, who
was the guide for the group, was dead. The robbers fled to the
southwest and split into two groups. The James brothers es-
caped to Missouri. The Youngers and Charlie Pitts tried to flee,
but got lost in the area. A posse, organized by Jesse Ames, lost
their trail on the 14th. On the 21st a young boy, Asle Oscar
Sorbel, whose identity was not generally made known until
1929, spotted the group. Over the objections of his doubting
parents he went to Madelia and reported what he had seen.
Sheriff James Glispin organized a group that captured the
Youngers in Hanska Slough. Pitts was killed in this fight.
There is an amusing footnote to this story. Cadavers were in
short supply at medical schools in 1876. The Northfield towns-
people quickly buried Stiles and Miller, but Wheeler and two
Action in the street. Woodcut from John Jay Lemon, The Northfield Tragedy (1876).
Gang spilt up here
on way to robbery
Frank and Jesse
James rode stolen
horses Into South
Dakota on Sept. 17
•
St James
St. Paul
•
Bank held up
Sept. 7, 1876
N Northheicl
Millersburg
Shieldsrdle
Cordova
Gorman
Lake
'9 •
unO11
Cannon Cry
•/
Cry
The group split up
here Sept. 14
Chortle PIRs
three Younger brothers
captured on foot hare
Sept. 21
lako.
Lake
• Crystal
Hansks
Tweet
More like this
- Paper Money- Vol. XXXVIII, No. 6- Whole No. 204- November- December 1999
- Paper Money- Vol. XXVII, No. 6- Whole No. 138- November- December 1988
- Paper Money- Vol. XXXVII, No. 6- Whole No. 198- November- December 1998
- Paper Money- Vol. LIII, No. 6- Whole No. 294- November/December 2014
- Paper Money- Vol. LIV, No. 6- Whole No. 300- November/December 2015
S
P
M
C
Privacy Policy | Terms of Service © 2024 SPMC Inc. All Rights Reserved.